Elsevier

Energy Policy

Volume 35, Issue 11, November 2007, Pages 5354-5369
Energy Policy

Climate change, mitigation and adaptation with uncertainty and learning

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2006.01.031Get rights and content

Abstract

One of the major issues in climate change policy is how to deal with the considerable uncertainty that surrounds many of the elements. Some of these uncertainties will be resolved through the process of further research. This process of learning raises a crucial timing question: should society delay taking action in anticipation of obtaining better information, or should it accelerate action, because we might learn that climate change is much more serious than expected. Much of the analysis to date has focussed on the case where the actions available to society are just the mitigation of emissions, and where there is little or no role for learning. We extend the analysis to allow for both mitigation and adaptation. We show that including adaptation weakens the effect of the irreversibility constraint and so, for this model, makes it more likely that the prospect of future learning should lead to less action now to deal with climate change. We review the empirical literature on climate change policy with uncertainty, learning, and irreversibility, and show that to date the effects on current policy are rather small, though this may reflect the particular choice of models employed.

Introduction

One of the major issues in climate change policy is how to deal with the considerable uncertainty that surrounds many of the elements needed, in terms of the scientific understanding of the processes driving climate change, for example, the risk of possible catastrophic effects of climate change, the impacts of any such changes on society and the economy, the extent to which these impacts might be ameliorated by future adaptation and the economic values to be attached to these impacts, for example, the appropriate social discount rate or equity weights.

This raises the obvious question of how such uncertainties should affect decisions about the current level of abatement of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and hence about the correct amount of mitigation and adaptation. What would be the difference if explicit account is taken of uncertainties as opposed to ignoring such uncertainties?

However, there is a more subtle aspect to the treatment of uncertainties, which is the focus of this paper. For some of these uncertainties will be resolved through the process of further research, for example, as exemplified in the reports of the IPCC. This process of learning raises a crucial timing question: should society delay taking action to reduce GHG emissions in anticipation of obtaining better information, or should it accelerate action, because we might learn that climate change is much more serious than expected but find that by the time we learn this information we have too little time to adjust. But this timing question also needs to take account of the fact that there are constraints on how quickly the stock of GHGs can be reduced in the future. So, if society learns that the damages from climate change are much greater than currently expected, it may not be able to take as much action to reduce the stock of gases as it would ideally like to take. This constraint is referred to as an irreversibility constraint. Much of the analysis of this timing question to date has focussed on the case where the actions available to society are just the mitigation of emissions. We extend the analysis to allow for both mitigation and adaptation, by extending the model of Ulph and Ulph (1997). We show that the inclusion of adaptation weakens the impact of the irreversibility constraint, so that for this model it is more likely that the prospect of future learning should lead society to take less action now to deal with climate change.

In Section 2, we summarise the theoretical results, which are set out fully in Appendix A. Firstly, those for where the only policy with regard to climate change is the mitigation of GHG emissions. Starting from a two-period model in which there is no uncertainty and no irreversibility, irreversibility, and uncertainty with the possibility of learning are introduced into this model, the consequences for optimal mitigation are derived. Then adaptation is introduced into the model in two ways. The first way is that adaptation acts in a way equivalent to a reduction in the stock of GHGs, the second is that adaptation reduces marginal damage costs. The general conclusion from these admittedly very simple models is that allowing for adaptation reduces the relevance of the irreversibility constraint, and results depend more on the pure learning effect.

In Section 3, we survey the attempts that have been made to assess the implications of uncertainty, irreversibility, learning and precaution in the context of empirical models of climate change. These studies suggest that the prospect of obtaining better information (earlier resolution of uncertainty) should lead to a reduction in current abatement levels, although these effects are small. Contrary to the simple intuition of the precautionary principle, with the exception of one scenario, all these studies suggest that the prospect of obtaining better information (earlier resolution of uncertainty) should lead to a reduction in current abatement levels, although these effects are small. However, the theoretical analysis of Section 2 would suggest that these results are not very surprising given the choice of utility functions (either logarithmic or quadratic) and that the environmental irreversibility constraint does not seem to bite even in worst-state scenarios.

Section snippets

Uncertainty, learning, irreversibility and precaution

We explore the implications of allowing for the fact that decision-makers know that over time they are likely to obtain new information which will help them resolve some of the uncertainties about climate change, when the stock of GHGs is irreversible. The standard intuition is that if one is making an irreversible decision under uncertainty when there is the prospect of obtaining better information in the future, then this should reduce the extent to which one makes irreversible commitments in

Empirical models of irreversibility, learning, mitigation and adaptation

In this section, we briefly review the attempts that have been made to assess the implications of uncertainty, irreversibility, learning and precaution in the context of empirical models of climate change. As we noted in the introduction almost all the empirical work we are aware of deals only with models where the only policy instruments are controls on emissions of GHGs. We begin by summarising this literature, and then turn to one aspect of empirical analysis of adaptation and learning.

Conclusions

We have considered models of optimal climate change policy towards mitigation and adaptation when there is uncertainty, learning and irreversibility. Earlier theoretical literature had focussed on the case where the only policy is mitigation of emissions. This paper considers the extension to include adaptation.

In the theoretical section of the paper, we began by reviewing the results of the Ulph and Ulph (1997) model in which there is only mitigation, as a way of illustrating the main factors

References (28)

  • C. Henry

    Investment decisions under uncertainty: the irreversibility effect

    American Economic Review

    (1974)
  • C. Henry

    Option values in economics of irreplaceable assets

    Review of Economic Studies

    (1974)
  • A. Ingham et al.

    Uncertainty, irreversibility, precaution, and the social cost of carbon

  • Ingham, A., Ma, J., Ulph, A., 2005a. How do the costs of adaptation affect optimal mitigation when there is...
  • Cited by (60)

    • The strategic role of adaptation in international environmental agreements

      2024, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
    • The climate change strategies of seaports: Mitigation vs. adaptation

      2020, Transportation Research Part D: Transport and Environment
      Citation Excerpt :

      One major drawback of such general setting is that it lacks the context to discuss the role of market interactions in determining the impacts of the climate strategies. Ingham et al. (2007) build a framework to incorporate uncertainty, learning, and both types of climate change strategies. They show that including adaptation would in fact lead to less action now to deal with climate change due to the prospect of future learning.

    • The Economic Value of Climate Information in Adaptation Decisions: Learning in the Sea-level Rise and Coastal Infrastructure Context

      2018, Ecological Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Consequently, it is thought to be particularly useful for infrastructure-based investment decisions that need to account for climate change risks (Glanemann, 2014). Possible improvements in computer processing capabilities, combined with developments in climate science and improved knowledge of the extent and timing of climate change risks as a result of improvements in climate data, are recognised as offering potential means through which learning can occur (Ingham et al., 2007; Hulme and Dessai, 2008; Glanemann, 2014). Current practice has been slow to adopt these decision methods in adaptation appraisal; anecdotal evidence suggests that their relative complexity and resource-intensiveness may be responsible for the low level of take-up (Herder et al., 2011).

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    This paper is produced as part of a project on “The Economic Analysis of Adaptation and Mitigation”. We are grateful to the Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research for support for this project.

    View full text